Is China
Killing
The WTO?
THE INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY. WINTER 2010
Chinese officials are
ignoring both
international and local
law for companies that
produce for export.
For fifteen long years, the members of the
GATT/WTO debated whether they would be better
off with China as a member. Trade policymakers
understood that the international organization could
not pretend to govern world trade with such an
important trading nation outside of the World Trade
Organization. They wagered that China’s trade policy
would become more predictable, accessible, and
transparent. Moreover, they concluded that member states could collaborate,
using the WTO’s rules, to prod China to act responsibly as a
global trader. China acceded to the WTO in 2001.
To some degree that bet has “paid off,” producing benefits for the citizens
of China and other countries. Trade has helped China lift some four
hundred million people out of poverty and has provided more of the
Chinese people with greater access to opportunities. Foreign investors
and producers now serve China’s growing market, while consumers
worldwide can purchase a broad range of well-made affordable goods
made in China. Meanwhile, Chinese demand for goods and raw materials
has created jobs and stimulated economic growth in many developing
countries. The World Bank notes that the efficiency and scale of
China’s manufacturing has pushed down the prices of many manufactured
products relative to other goods and services.
B Y S USAN A RIEL A ARONSON
Chinese officials are
ignoring both
international and local
law for companies that
produce for export.
Susan Ariel Aaronson is an Associate Research Professor and
2009–2010 Policy Research Scholar, George Washington University
Elliott School. This article is a shorter version of a chapter prepared
for the forthcoming book, China in the WTO: An Early Harvest (Petros
Mavroidis, ed.).
THE MAGAZINE OF INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC POLICY
888 16th Street, N.W., Suite 740
Washington, D.C. 20006
Phone: 202-861-0791 • Fax: 202-861-0790
www.international-economy.com
WINTER 2010 THE INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY 41
A ARONSON
China today is now the world’s third-largest trading
nation, the world’s largest recipient of investment, the
world’s fastest growing consumer market, and the world’s
leading provider of manufactured goods. China’s regulatory
and trade practices can move global markets.
But China’s competitive advantage is to some degree
based on its inadequate governance—it fails to enforce its
own laws in a transparent, evenhanded manner. China’s
system is broken. And because it is broken, its inadequate
governance affects its trade partners—and ultimately, could
break the WTO.
On the one hand, China’s leaders have tried very hard
to comply with the country’s WTO obligations. China has
changed many of its laws and met most of its market access
commitments. On the other hand, it has yet to meet many
of the obligations delineated in its protocol of accession.
European and American business groups investing in China
perceive China as becoming more interventionist and protectionist.
As the world’s most populous country, China is in
many ways an outlier. It is both an ancient empire and
developing country with two key attributes: authoritarian
governance and inadequate governance. At the national
level, the Communist Party is at times willing to ignore its
international commitments in order to maintain power.
Moreover, the Communist Party owns and operates, or is
tied to, private enterprises in key sectors such as transportation,
energy, and banking. Some have described the
government as both a market competitor and a referee.
China’s inadequate governance at the provincial level
also reflects many factors including corruption, a lack of
uniformity among rules, and arbitrary abuse of power.
Local officials often have financial stakes in the same companies
they are supposed to regulate. The Communist Party
and business are deeply intertwined, and thus governmental
mandates from Beijing may be ignored or circumvented.
Finally, China has a culture of noncompliance, where bad
actors set the norm, where laws and regulations are often
ignored or unevenly enforced, and where many citizens
and market actors don’t know or can’t obtain their rights
under the law.
WTO members deliberated a long time before they
let China join the WTO. And they used the accession to
hold China on a tight leash. The 2001 Protocol on the
Accession of the People’s Republic of China explicitly
calls on China to “apply and administer in a uniform,
impartial, and reasonable manner all its laws, regulations
and other measures of the central government as well as
local regulations, rules and other measures…pertaining to
or affecting trade…. China shall establish a mechanism
under which individuals and enterprises can bring to the
attention of the national authorities cases of non-uniform
application.” It also calls on China to ensure that “those
laws, regulations, and other measures pertaining to and
affecting trade…shall be enforced.” The rule of law was a
key element of China’s accession agreement because trade
policymakers understood that how China was governed
could distort trade in many of the sectors in which China
competes.
In recent years, China has become infamous for its failure
to enforce its own laws, whether those laws related to
intellectual property, product or food safety, human rights,
or employment. In both its 2006 and 2008 Trade Policy
Review at the WTO, member states lauded Chinese trade
diplomats for their export prowess, but also complained that
China was not transparent, accountable, or sufficiently evenhanded.
Nor could they trust Chinese statistics on trade,
economic growth, bank stability, intellectual property protection,
and other aspects of enforcement.
Despite their frustrations with China and the weakness
of the WTO, WTO members have the ability to
address its inadequate governance. Scholars such as Robert
Staiger, Kyle Bagwell, Petros Mavroidis, and Drusilla
Brown have identified a means under WTO rules to challenge
China’s trade practices. As Brown has noted, “Under
GATT Article XXIII, any country in the WTO is entitled to
a ‘right of redress’ for changes in domestic policy that erode
market access commitments even if no explicit GATT rule
has been violated. Such a ‘non-violation’ complaint entitles
the aggrieved party either to compensation in the form of
other tariff concessions to ‘rebalance’ market access commitments
or the complaining partner may withdraw equivalent
concessions of its own.” Legal scholars agree with
this interpretation. According to Joost Pauwelyn, professor
of international law at the Graduate Institute of
International Studies in Geneva, “In non-violation cases a
WTO panel could, indeed, be called upon to refer to nonWTO
rules […] in its assessment of whether certain governmental
measures, though not in violation of WTO rules,
have affected the ‘legitimate expectations’ that could have
been derived from a trade concession.” A complaint based
China’s competitive advantage
is to some degree based on
its inadequate governance.
Continued on page 67
WINTER 2010 THE INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY 67
A ARONSON
on this argument might proceed as follows: When China
joined the WTO, Chinese leaders agreed to enforce their laws
and provide duty-free access for our products such as iPods
or Heineken beers. We anticipated that you would respect
international standards (for consumer safety, product safety or
workers rights, for example.) But a wide range of observers—
Chinese and foreign—have carefully researched Chinese
practices and have reported that Chinese officials ignore both
international and local laws in factories that produce for
export (such as those that supply foreign companies) as well
as Chinese factories that compete with Apple or Heineken.
Thus, your country has violated these non-WTO rules, and in
so doing has impeded our access to markets; thus, we are
requesting compensation for the value of that lost access.
Such a trade dispute may not succeed because it would
be hard to prove that market access was undermined by
China’s failure to enforce its own laws and international standards.
But a multilateral approach would bring the issue to
global attention and could move China to do a better job of
educating managers, policymakers, and workers on the
importance of the rule of law.
China’s membership in the WTO has no doubt provided
benefits for the people of the world. But China is exporting its
inadequate governance. At the WTO, member states can work
collectively to encourage China to change its behavior. And
in so doing, they may bolster the WTO. A broken China need
not destroy the WTO.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Comments always welcome!